US Rebalancing, a looming liquidity crisis, and the RMB

The election of Donald Trump as the new President of the United States is, in the  view of  advocates and critics, a game-changer. Spanning  reshoring manufacturing jobs,  taxation and infrastructure investments,  President Trump’s  political economy  connotes  a significant paradigm shift , that in  almost in one stroke  plans a  return   to the real  economy engine, and break off the era of US as the consumer of last resort. 
In this context the  “manufacturing renaissance”, as it is dubbed,  plays  the pivot of  the new US  economic paradigm,  and  is  not  only  a political catchphrase.
Due to the  new technologies to extract low-cost natural gas, energy  by itself   hands  a substantial advantage to  manufacturing  based in US. Natural gas prices, according to The Boston Consulting Group,    are calculated to be   90% higher in the United Kingdom, 180% higher in France, 190% higher in Germany, and 240% higher in Japan,  and the  industrial electricity prices  150% higher in France, 180% higher in the United Kingdom, 100% higher in Germany, and 150% higher in Japan than in the United States.
In sum, total manufactured costs vis-à-vis  US  peers group  including  France, Germany  and Japan  are respectively higher by  15%  to  21% , and  productivity-adjusted wages  for US based manufacturing   about 33% lower than Japan and 25% lower than Germany.
 Energy boom and cheaper energy costs, notably natural gas, have  been the single major factor in  shrinking the  US trade deficit, from 5.6 percent of gross domestic product in 2006 to 3 percent in 2015.
On the side of labor costs, US wages compared with emerging market economies in Asia, a preferred  foreign direct investment destination of US multinationals,  low wages are no more a boon.  Since 2001, hourly manufacturing wages in China have been rising  by an average of 12% a year, so the  China’s  wage advantage   actually  is thinning to a  less 10 percent.
A  sensible motive for returning  jobs on the American soil. It  lies  on the assumption that manufacturing has a high employment multiplier,  a large amount of ancillary jobs  generated in other fields. Projections based on Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA)  calculated that a dollar’s worth of final demand for manufacturers generates $1.48 in other services and production.  In contrast the retail and wholesale trade sectors have much lower multipliers, generating 54 cents and 58 cents respectively in other additional inputs for every dollar of economic activity they generate (Stephen Gold, MAPI).

There is also a further reason for  the  “Manufacturing Renaissance” to play high in the new Administration’s political agenda: Fix the high-powered political issue of the US  current account deficit, which though since 6.4 percent of GDP in 2005,  800 billion dollars or 1.8 percent of the  world GDP,  has declined to a safe 2.6 percent of current-dollar GDP, , it’s is still a high-powered political issue.

Atish Ghosh and Uma Ramakrishnan write: “When countries run large deficits, businesses, trade unions, and parliamentarians are often quick to point accusing fingers at trading partners and make charges about unfair practices” (   ) .

Aside from goods and services, the current account is also influenced by a nation’s excess of investment over saving.  Since the 80ties  US gross saving has fallen as a share of GDP. Households, rather than firms, and government  seem to be co-responsible for this trend. Moreover, while the decline in saving may reflect the decline in inflation, low interest rates, budgetary policies have also fuelled what might  seems a structural  shortage of domestic finance available for productive investment.
Tensions between the United States  and China   over  whom should be held responsible  for trade imbalance   has urged  to consider  the broader consequences for the international financial system when some countries run large and persistent current account deficits and others accumulate big surpluses” .
If these actions  tell a story, it is that the U.S. political leaders are making the most of the Great Financial Crisis. Rebalancing America’s growth engine on real economy, US stubborn current account imbalance will return on a healthier and stable path.    
Yet, this uplifting story has downsides.
For one,  getting  rid of trade deficit  could have  upshots on  inflation rates, and even and flight on the dollar.  Patrick  Artus  of Natixis has elaborated  on the idea often floated of eliminating  US non-energy trade deficit by means of  taxation imports.  Under the assumption that will be no retaliation and that US exports remain unchanged, US should  reduce foreign imports by 17 percent. Given the low price elasticity of US imports in volume terms (0.08), this would require astronomical customs tariffs of 212%, which translates into 30 per cent higher US domestic prices, which are likely offset by a redistribution of the proceeds of the tax on imports. Higher inflation would push Fed to drastic  of rise interest rates, and flight from money. While the rest of the world  would suffer 0.8 percent from the loss of 17 percent in exports.
In conclusion,  Artus argues that a policy based on rebalancing  US trade deficit via customs tariffs make no sense.
 Besides the inflationary effects that will arise from a customs duties,   shrinking imports from foreign producers generates negative spillovers  in US domestic investment. “In a typical year, Griswold argues, foreigners take about $500 billion of what they earn selling US imported goods and services and use those dollars to acquire U.S. assets. That’s another way of saying our $500 billion current account deficit is exactly offset by a $500 billion investment surplus. The net inflow of foreign capital allows our level of domestic investment to exceed our level of national savings, fueling productivity and growth. If politicians try to “fix” the trade deficit, they will only succeed in cutting off the net inflow of foreign investment, leading to higher interest rates and less investment in foreign-owned factories”.
  Financial  spillovers from a US current account’s shrinkage  are also to spread to emerging markets.  As Andrew Sheng put it  “ the time will come when the U.S. economy shrinks its current account deficit and decreases dollar liquidity, creating a debt-deflation trap for the emerging world”.
A shrinking U.S. current account deficit, a rising dollar matched to a flight-to-quality, and especially a reduction of U.S. dollar exports due to the US energy independence  reduce the supply of dollars in the global economy. A serious question arises over what factors are likely to cause the U.S. to rebalance the global economy, especially for those countries that most rely on the U.S. dollar. In economics terms, this signals the Triffin dilemma. The always-useful Wikipedia definition states:
“The Triffin dilemma or paradox is the conflict of economic interests that arises between short-term domestic and long-term international objectives when a national currency also serves as a world reserve currency. The dilemma of choosing between these objectives was first identified in the 1960s by Belgian-American economist Robert Triffin. He pointed out that the country whose currency, being the global reserve currency, foreign nations wish to hold, must be willing to supply the world with an extra supply of its currency to fulfill world demand for these foreign exchange reserves.”
A reduction in the supply of dollars and a stronger dollar value, which are legitimate outcomes of national policymakers, are set to trigger a credit crunch and increase expenses for developing dollar-dependent economies with trade currencies and foreign reserves denominated in U.S. dollars.
 Emerging economies, which are still the most dollar-dependent, are set to take the brunt, as they are mostly required to pay for trade transactions in U.S. dollars.
The dollar is still abundant because the Fed is stuck at a zero rate. Yet a shrinking supply is expected to occur faster than anticipated. Questions arise regarding whether the present international monetary system under the Fed’s leadership is willing to supply emergency funds on a whopping scale. Should a full-size liquidity crisis develop, where would fresh liquidity come from to keep the world economy going? The leading central banks do not step up to provide compensating liquidity for the rest of the world, which is still growing faster than the advanced countries, then there will be a credit crunch.”
The above questions are not negligible, given that emerging and developing economies dependent on the dollar make up more than half of global GDP. A liquidity crisis could not only hit emerging and developing economies. If it were to materialize, it would clearly cause a global economic contraction.
The gloomy scenario is evidence that the current monetary system is fated to fall under the gyrations of the US economic and monetary policy  once again. Capital flows are still driven by rising dollar  as episodes  appeared since the  Fed’s tapering, 2013, and recently in the wake of Fed’s rate hike and Trump’s win.  The global financial drive of the dollar  generate more harm than benefits. Capital outflows from emerging economies and even from Europe will  eventually push  central banks to increase interest rates at the detriment of  the global economy.
What the way out? The  classical Triffin solution  assumes  that fixing the problem with an alternative reserve currency is inherently impossible, as “my currency, your problem”  will fatally resurface.  The only solution for him  is a kind of synthetic “global currency” resulting from a balanced basket of major currencies.
Still, fresh evolutionary dynamics featured by spillbacks on the US Treasuries,   the internationalization  of the renminbi (RMB), and the ongoing US rebalancing signal  a decrease of  the US dollar dominance. President  Trump’s renegotiation of  continental  trade deals, and the  termination  of  two transcontinental  trade  projects  seems as Philip Stephens  wrote “Washington is edging back from the liberal order it created after the second world war” . Markets are  welcoming the yuan, as yesterday did  for  the euro, a sign  that geopolitical forces influence the trajectories of new reserve currencies.    If  China will take on her shoulders  the onus  to maintain it,   and will  not  put up  a diverse alternative,  the RMB  could  sooner than later play a role as a major reserve currency.

Share

Lascia un commento

Il tuo indirizzo email non sarà pubblicato. I campi obbligatori sono contrassegnati *